登陆注册
9701500000063

第63章 《佃农理论》英语原著 (57)

The ranking of vegetable crops in terms of percentage increases in crop area allows us to detect two patterns of choice implied by the hypothesis of increased farming intensity. First, we find the more frequent choice of a crop (higher percentage increase in crop area) which takes a shorter time to grow. This pattern is particularly clear in comparing items 1,9, 13, and 14. In general, stem (item 1) and leaf (item 9) vegetables grow faster than fruit (item 13) and root (item 14) vegetables. With a few exceptions which may be explained by another detected pattern, the growing time as a criterion of choice is also clearly shown by comparing vegetables of the same type: for example, among the listed root vegetables the highest ranked, radish (item 4), is noted as the fastest growing, whereas ginger (item 19) and dasheen (item 20) are "notoriously" slow; among fruit vegetables the highest ranked, tomato (item 6), perhaps grows the fastest; and among stem vegetables the lowest ranked, water convolvulus (item 17), is notably slow growing.[20]

Second, we find the more frequent choice of a crop which costs more to cultivate. Take Chinese cabbage and cabbage, for example; both crops require roughly the same growing time (about 95 days). But it is estimated that Chinese cabbage (item 2) requires 354 labor days for the cultivation of one acre, compared with 256 labor days for cabbage (item 5).[21]

The "time" and "cost" criteria of vegetable crop choice can be resolved into one: the maximization of income from land subject to a higher tenant cost constraint under the share restriction.

Under a competitive market, and provided that a crop is grown, a higher cost of production is associated with a higher value. Given the same growing time for different crops, those added more frequently at the margin under the share restriction were those which had a higher planting cost. On the other hand, given the same cost requirement of cultivation, the marginal crops more frequently added were those which required a shorter time, so that the given land could be released sooner for other crops. Both choices are implied by my theory, the results of a tendency toward the maximization of gross crop value rather than the crop value net of nonland costs.

[1]. See, for example, Cheng Chen, Record of Taiwan Land Reform, chaps. 1 and 2; JCRR, "JCRR Annual Reports," chaps. 1 and 2. Note that within paddy fields or dry land, the land prices vary according to soil grades and locations. In general, prefectures with higher rental percentages were associated with higher land prices. As was discerned in chap. 2, however, the market rental percentage depends not only on the fertility of land and the cost of farming, but also on the input commitments shared by the contracting parties. Although the price of land is the more appropriate measure for land fertility, for our present purpose the initial rental percentage is the relevant measure.

[2]. See Peterson, "Economic Study of Land Use."

[3]. The market rentals reported for these three prefectures usually range from 50 to 70 percent of the annual yield, though on some tenant farms a 90 percent rental share was observed. See Chen, Records of Taiwan Land Reform, chaps. 1 and 2; and JCRR, "Annual Reports," chaps. 1 and 2.

[4]. See the footnote attached to table 4 for prefecture delineation,

[5]. In 1948, the number of workers per tenant household was as follows: Sinchu, 7.28; Taipei, 6.97; Taichung, 6.21; Kaoshiung, 6.03; Tainan, 6.05; Hwalien, 6.32; Taitung, 5.21; and Penghu, 3.28. See DAF, Yearbook 1949, sec. 2.

[6]. Theoretically, the maximization of yield value per acre of land implies that the marginal product of tenant input has fallen to zero. Here we are only concerned with the tendency toward this condition.

[7]. It is reported that some tenants grew citronella illegally on the external land margin owned by the state. The crop area for citronella has declined since 1951, and particularly after the Land-to-the-Tiller program in 1953, so much so that the JCRR considered subsidizing its cultivation in 1960. See DAF, Yearbook 1958, sec. 3. 1. 18; and Shen, Agricultural Development on Taiwan, p. 108.

[8]. That is, during the share restriction the increase in crop area of citronella planting (faster rate) was proportionately greater than the decrease in crop area (hectare) yield, which led to a higher total output on the given land.

[9]. See Lu, Analysis of Farm Family Economy, p. 124; Shen, Agricultural Development on Taiwan, chap. 8 and particularly pp. 155-64; DAF, Yearbook 1948-52, sec. 3, 2; and Young-chi Tsui, A Study of Peanuts in Taiwan (Taipei: JCRR, 1954).

[10]. See Shen, Agricultural Development on Taiwan.

[11]. Tsung-han Shen, Agricultural Resources of China (New York: Cornell University Press, 1951), p. 220. This particular paragraph refers to peasants in Canton, China.

[12]. Unlike citronella, the hectare yield for the marginal crops listed in tables 6 and 7 usually started to decline in 1949, with the lowest hectare yield realized either in 1950 or in 1951. See DAF, Yearbook 1952, Sec. 3. 4. B. Both for clarity of presentation and for ironing out occasionally "erratic" output changes inherent in agriculture, the averages of a three-year period (1949-51) are used. Since the share restriction was imposed in April-June 1949, the confirmation of my hypothesis would be more critically displayed if these averages were taken for 1950-51.

[13]. Shen, Agricultural Resources of China, chap. 24.

[14]. On the average, the labor required to plant one crop hectare of vegetables is about seven times greater than for a common crop, and about five times greater than for a special crop. See Lu, Analysis of Farm Family Economy, p. 142, table 121.

[15]. Ibid. According to Lu, the labor required to cultivate green manure is about one-fiftieth of that required for vegetables.

[16]. A condition implied by a competitive market. For the market values of vegetables and other crops, see DAF, Yearbook 1952, sec. 3. B.

同类推荐
  • 35岁前要活学活用的经济学通识

    35岁前要活学活用的经济学通识

    在现实中,我们的生活时刻被经济的影子所萦绕,无论做什么都充满着经济的味道。经常关注各大门户网站的人,很容易就会总结出目前中国的热点问题,所有这些问题没有一个不与经济学密切相关,也没有一个不与老百姓的切身利益密切相关,有心者也许还会注意到,我们的一举一动几乎都与经济学有着千丝万缕的联系。例如,就业市场风云变幻,当初的热门专业早已“降温”,年轻人求职很难不受此影响;房市前景未明,房价似乎按兵不动,不知道什么时候买房才合适……
  • 中国股票市场改革与发展研究

    中国股票市场改革与发展研究

    本书从股票和股票市场的基本概念讲起,总结了股票市场18年的改革开放和不断发展的历程,对股票市场形成的内在机理、发展规律进行归纳总结和逻辑分析,力图给读者一个比较清晰的股票市场改革与发展的脉络和线索。
  • 黄冈国家地理标志产品开发战略研究

    黄冈国家地理标志产品开发战略研究

    该项目的研究是对地理标志产品开发实践的深该总结,也是对黄冈市今后发展地标产品的科学规划和正确引导,将为政府决策、争取政策、项目支持和招商引资提供详实资料和理论依据,为促进黄冈市农业产业化、推进黄冈经济社会全面发展提供有力支持。
  • 综合营销策划

    综合营销策划

    本书共分15个章节,内容包括综合营销策划总论、营销策划创意、营销策划模式与营销策划书、SWOT分析、企业营销定位策划、市场竞争策划、企业形象策划等。
  • 后天有多远?

    后天有多远?

    当今世界,气候危机、能源危机和金融危机三重危机叠加出现,三重危机的核心是能源,为了走出这三重危机的阴影,人们寄希望于低碳能源的新能源,希望通过它“毕其功于一役”,然而,现实是残酷的,至少在未来几十年内,没有一种能源形式能够替代以石油为代表的化石能源,那么,在三重危机之下,我们不禁要问:后天有多远?后天之后,我们又该去向何方?本书所讨论的正是这三种危机之间的深层次的相互关系。
热门推荐
  • 寻找

    寻找

    本书主要内容为:酸楚的日子,苦涩的初恋,快乐的时光,多变的季节。
  • 剑石界

    剑石界

    一笑机缘巧合,拔出真我之剑,立志成为大英雄、大豪杰!!PS:喜欢本书的朋友,加qq群:469295579
  • 我真的平亿近人

    我真的平亿近人

    叮:恭喜你已经游戏一个小时,获得奖金100元。……当程歌耳边响起这样的声音刹那,他知道迎娶白富美的人生巅峰就要来了! 又名神豪养成日记,一切从游戏开始。
  • 神妃在上墨许三生

    神妃在上墨许三生

    韶韵山被围困,桃亦墨逃亡灵界调查,却不想牵扯到一千年前的真相……
  • 魂绕古希腊哈迪斯的冥后

    魂绕古希腊哈迪斯的冥后

    图书馆里看了一本小说,小说里一个女孩穿越过去当了哈迪斯的宠妃?叶蹁跹简直想骂死作者。谁不知道哈迪斯多么爱他的冥后?随后,她竟穿越到了小说里!哈迪斯!你爱的只能是珀耳塞福涅!什么?我也不能!奇伦在叶蹁跹旁边问道:你爱的是我吧?叶蹁跹:我爱的是你……座下的一个男孩啊!
  • 替身宫女倾后宫:公主心计

    替身宫女倾后宫:公主心计

    她扮作宫女,想逃过一劫,却不料他独独抓了她,充作奴婢。百般的折辱,动辄得咎,他是她眼中的恶魔。他留给她无尽的羞辱和痛苦,她是他脚下最卑贱的奴婢。他灭了她的国,害死她的父兄,最后还要拿掉她腹中的孩子他冷酷地笑:“你不配有朕的孩子,你一生都是最卑贱的罪婢!”
  • 天行

    天行

    号称“北辰骑神”的天才玩家以自创的“牧马冲锋流”战术击败了国服第一弓手北冥雪,被誉为天纵战榜第一骑士的他,却受到小人排挤,最终离开了效力已久的银狐俱乐部。是沉沦,还是再次崛起?恰逢其时,月恒集团第四款游戏“天行”正式上线,虚拟世界再起风云!
  • 命运的安排

    命运的安排

    因为一个梦,让我人生从此不同。。。。。。
  • 假如给我三天光明

    假如给我三天光明

    假如你的一生只有三天能看到光明,你会拿来做什么?海伦说,她会好好看看这个世界,看那绚烂的色彩,看那雄伟的建筑,看至亲之人的面孔……
  • 影响力 意志力 创新力

    影响力 意志力 创新力

    本书是励志类读物,该书在总结众多成功人士经验的基础上,全面、深入地揭示了影响力、意志力和创新力的内涵和现实意义,为人们详尽提供了发掘和提升影响力、意志力和创新力的有效方案和途径,帮助他们在今后的生活实践中,打造强大影响力,锤炼坚忍不拔的意志力,培养良好的创新习惯和思维,从而有效应对纷繁复杂和竞争激烈的时代,拓展事业和生活空间,成就辉煌事业和美好人生。